The challenges of modeling presidential tax plans

In modeling presidential tax plans, several things need to be considered, among them the net economic impact of an explicit trade-off of higher taxes for new spending programs and the relationship between tax changes and the overall economy.

|
Tom Lynn/AP/File
Democratic presidential candidates Sen. Bernie Sanders, I-Vt, left, and Hillary Clinton take the stage before a Democratic presidential primary debate at the University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, in Milwaukee (Feb. 11, 2016).

The Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget sponsored a fascinating discussion yesterday on estimating presidential candidate tax plans. My Tax Policy Center colleague Len Burman,  Kyle Pomerleau of the Tax Foundation, and Bob McIntyre of Citizens for Tax Justice made one thing clear: Modeling these plans is a bit like playing three-dimensional chess.

To understand what these tax plans mean, you need to start by doing what TPC does, model their revenue and distributional effects. But you also have to consider at least three other issues: the net economic impact of an explicit trade-off of higher taxes for new spending programs, the relationship between tax changes and the overall economy, and the impact of bigger deficits on economic growth.

Let’s look at them one at a time:

The tax and spending swap. This is a particular challenge when thinking about Bernie Sanders, who has proposed massive new spending programs and huge tax increases to fund them. The Sanders campaign correctly says it is important to acknowledge that there is an explicit trade-off in a plan that asks people to pay higher taxes to fund universal health care, which would eliminate their need to buy health insurance.

But currently that’s beyond the capacity of tax modelers. We are the Tax Policy Center, not the spending policy center. Kyle would probably say the same thing about the Tax Foundation. Calculating the trade-offs for the Sanders health and education plans requires sophisticated spending models that we don’t have (though we are working on it).

Taxes and the economy. How much do tax changes affect the economy, and, in turn, what do those economic effects mean for the revenue cost of a reworked tax code?

This issue is key to understanding the enormous tax cuts being proposed by three of the four remaining Republicans hopefuls—Donald Trump, Marco Rubio, and Ted Cruz. Each insists his initiative would result in long-run economic growth that would offset much of the revenue loss from the tax cuts. They say they’d pay for the rest with largely unspecified reductions in spending.

The Tax Foundation, which supports tax cuts, has concluded that each of these plans would work roughly as promised. For example, it estimates that Rubio’s tax plan would lose about $6.1 trillion over 10 years using traditional ”static”  budget scoring (which accounts for behavioral responses to tax changes but not added growth). But by taking into account those macroeconomic effects (using what’s called dynamic scoring) the group found Rubio’s plan would lose much less--$2.4 trillion. TPC, which includes only behavioral changes in its estimates, projects the Rubio plan would add $6.8 trillion to the debt over the next decade.

Economists would love to understand how tax changes affect the economy. But forecasting those effects is very sensitive to assumptions about how wages, saving, and investment respond to tax changes. If you start by, say, assuming that lowering tax rates boosts economic activity, your model will, not surprisingly, tell you that a candidate’s plan to lower tax rates will create economic growth that will offset revenue loss.

Unfortunately, in a big, complex economy, it is hard to test these assumptions. So they fall into the realm of informed speculation.

We do know that real world experiments, such as the 1981 tax cuts or the 1986 tax reform, have resulted in little or no changes in growth.  A paper by Dartmouth economist Andrew Samwick and my TPC colleague Bill Gale found surprisingly little added growth from those big tax changes.

Deficit effects. Even if tax cuts do generate growth, this year’s proposals are so big that they’ll still significantly increase deficits. But would those higher deficits boost interest rates so much that they’d wash out the benefits of the tax cuts?

For instance, let’s say you reduce the marginal tax rate on business investment. That should be good news for capital-intensive firms. But what happens if this and other tax changes generate a big increase in the federal debt that, in turn, drives up interest rates. Would firms still boost investment if they are hit with higher borrowing costs?

To answer that question, you need to answer two related and difficult questions. How much does a tax cut add to the debt (see question #2 above)? And can you predict what that additional borrowing will mean for future interest rates?

TPC hopes to weigh in on these difficult questions during the campaign. But finding answers is not easy.

This article first appeared at TaxVox.

You've read  of  free articles. Subscribe to continue.
Real news can be honest, hopeful, credible, constructive.
What is the Monitor difference? Tackling the tough headlines – with humanity. Listening to sources – with respect. Seeing the story that others are missing by reporting what so often gets overlooked: the values that connect us. That’s Monitor reporting – news that changes how you see the world.

Dear Reader,

About a year ago, I happened upon this statement about the Monitor in the Harvard Business Review – under the charming heading of “do things that don’t interest you”:

“Many things that end up” being meaningful, writes social scientist Joseph Grenny, “have come from conference workshops, articles, or online videos that began as a chore and ended with an insight. My work in Kenya, for example, was heavily influenced by a Christian Science Monitor article I had forced myself to read 10 years earlier. Sometimes, we call things ‘boring’ simply because they lie outside the box we are currently in.”

If you were to come up with a punchline to a joke about the Monitor, that would probably be it. We’re seen as being global, fair, insightful, and perhaps a bit too earnest. We’re the bran muffin of journalism.

But you know what? We change lives. And I’m going to argue that we change lives precisely because we force open that too-small box that most human beings think they live in.

The Monitor is a peculiar little publication that’s hard for the world to figure out. We’re run by a church, but we’re not only for church members and we’re not about converting people. We’re known as being fair even as the world becomes as polarized as at any time since the newspaper’s founding in 1908.

We have a mission beyond circulation, we want to bridge divides. We’re about kicking down the door of thought everywhere and saying, “You are bigger and more capable than you realize. And we can prove it.”

If you’re looking for bran muffin journalism, you can subscribe to the Monitor for $15. You’ll get the Monitor Weekly magazine, the Monitor Daily email, and unlimited access to CSMonitor.com.

QR Code to The challenges of modeling presidential tax plans
Read this article in
https://www.csmonitor.com/Business/Tax-VOX/2016/0315/The-challenges-of-modeling-presidential-tax-plans
QR Code to Subscription page
Start your subscription today
https://www.csmonitor.com/subscribe